Red Team Memo
In Spring 2023, our close contacts at a Global 50 law department asked us to write a ‘red team’ memorandum pointing out the potential pitfalls in a planned panel refresh.
Red Teaming
“Red teaming is the practice of rigorously challenging plans, policies, systems and assumptions by adopting an adversarial approach. A red team may be a contracted external party or an internal group that uses strategies to encourage an outsider perspective. The goal of red teaming is to overcome cognitive errors such as groupthink and confirmation bias, which can impair the decision-making or critical thinking ability of an individual or organization.”*
We wrote the memo.
But when we delivered the memo, we expressly predicted our contacts would not pass it onto the rest of the executive leadership team. We observed that for the truth to be palatable it would need to be watered down to the point of drowning.
The Road Not Taken
BACKGROUND
Anonymity limits the details we can share.
Suffice it to say, the requesting law department had already done all the things when it comes to outside counsel management. Convergence. Preferred provider panels. Discounts. Alternative fee arrangements. Reverse auctions. Value adds. Matter-level RFPs. Matter budgets. Outside counsel guidelines…all the things. With spectacular results, btw.
If some is good, more is better, no? New department leadership was interested in building on the success of the preferred provider program by doing all the things, again.
Our contacts immediately identified the issue: the traditional levers of reducing spend with outside counsel are subject to diminishing returns—done correctly, many are one-time lifts.
Our contacts also immediately identified the politics: sharing this uncomfortable truth would not land well with new leadership, who lacked not only the historical context but also the bandwidth to be brought up to speed—as is often the case, they wanted wins on the board ASAP and expected their direct reports to deliver on these dictates.
In a pickle, our contacts needed someone knowledgeable enough to articulate why doubling down was unlikely to double the results and stupid enough to say the quiet parts out loud. So, basically, Casey.
Casey wrote the red-team memo. But, turns out, the quiet parts are quiet for good reason. When you lay out what is required to push beyond the traditional modes of buying and delivering legal services, the conversation becomes real uncomfortable real quick.
It is all in the memo. In summary, law departments and law firms will need to do that which they were never designed to do: solve for scale. This requires re-engineering for which there is neither budget nor appetite. It requires fundamentally changing the relationship between the law department and the business. Infinitely easier said than done.
While the memo was not passed on, the effort was not wasted. Our contacts used the palatable pieces to make their case within the political constraints of their organization. We strongly warn against self-righteousness in assessing the decision about how much was shared. We should trust that people know their own organizational context. Compassion should be the default.
We live in the most exciting of times. But we also live in the most challenging. The era of stability is over. Many hard choices need to be made, including which battles to fight and when.
CAVEAT
In an information economy, attention is the scarcest commodity. We never expected the memo to be read in full by most. Rather, the body of the memo is reference material made available to answer specific questions raised by the Overview/Summary.
EXECUTIVE OVERVIEW
[REDACTED] has already established itself as a leader in leveraging purchasing power to secure below-market rates for legal services. Yet while extracting rate concessions and imposing budget discipline produce measurable benefits, these cost-control methods are subject to diminishing returns. There is little, if any, room for most incumbent providers to further maneuver on rates subject to the constraints of their own commercial imperatives.
(i) paying higher rates to incumbents or
(ii) switching to lower-cost providers.
Moreover, rate recalibrations resulting from moving work to lower-cost providers will still not result in an inflection point in the upward slope of overall legal spend. Indeed, even if a material shift in the organizational attitude towards new hires permitted aggressive insourcing, bringing work in-house would, at best, also only offer temporary relief.
(i) eliminating legal needs,
(ii) decreasing the labor intensity of legal service delivery, or
(iii) leaving some legal needs unmet.
Higher business velocity in an increasingly complex legal operating environment ensures that the business’s legal needs will expand, not contract. Not meeting business needs is patently unacceptable. Thus, the only viable path is a reducing labor intensity—i.e., scaling the delivery of legal services.
Scaling legal service delivery is genuinely hard. Success cannot be guaranteed. But satisfying ever-intensifying business needs through traditional means without a proportionate increase in resources is impossible. Failure is inevitable absent a meaningful structural shift. That is, either you bet on your own capacity to change or you bet you can muddle through until some massive external change makes it so you don’t have to.
PROGRAM SUMMARY
Structure.
01 Portfolio
02 Panel
03 Marketplace
04 Extraordinary
Flow.
- Systematically packaging meaningful tranches of work and entering portfolio-level arrangements geared towards solving for scale. Importantly, portfolios can be packaged over time—every portfolio need not be implemented immediately nor simultaneously—and are not limited to traditional law firm relationships (e.g., Integrated Law).
- Reducing the number of smaller panel arrangements and enabling the marketplace to absorb less frequent panel work because panels naturally skew towards larger, more expensive firms and the effort required to offset this skew—i.e., enlarging the panel—reintroduces variants of the administrative burden the panel was created to redress.
Objectives.
- Solving for scale. Reducing the ratio of legal resource inputs to business outcomes—not merely reducing the unit cost of legal labor (i.e., insourcing, discounts).
- Right sourcing. Ensuring capped internal headcount is directed to its optimal use while external legal labor reflects the proper mix of expertise and price level.
- Reducing administrative friction and refocusing administrative resources. As the program matures, re-allocating attention from ‘who’ gets the work to ‘how’ the work gets done.
- • Reframing DEI efforts. Centering the hiring and career progression of diverse professionals despite tradeoffs with other objectives (e.g., reducing administrative burden, maximizing savings).
- • Revisiting the entire value chain and utilizing all levers to drive cost-effectiveness. Taking a total-cost-of-ownership perspective grounded in business value.
ASSUMPTIONS
Law firms have their own commercial objectives and constraints. Just as with your employees, you can mandate a 20% cut in compensation along with a multi-year freeze. Some will stay. Some will leave and be replaced. You can repeat the exercise as often as you choose. But choices have consequences. Eventually, willingness to pay will shrink the available talent pool.
2. Law firm rates have increased.
Since 2015, billing rates for law firms have risen 30%, with larger firms up 38% and the biggest jumps coming since 2020. Thus far in 2023, rate increases are on an unprecedented pace, with average rates up 5.8% and the largest firms commanding an average increase of 7.3% over 2022 worked rates. Firms with rates essentially frozen since 2020 are likely to be seeking somewhere between a 15% and 30% increase and can credibly argue these rates are still substantially below market.
In addition to inflation, billed rates increase because professional services have thus far been less susceptible to productivity gains than other sectors. Empirical data supports the theory (Baumol’s cost disease) that this drives up the relative costs in labor-intensive sectors like law (in-house salaries follow the same pattern, just from a lower baseline).
The business operating environment continues to become more legally complex. Expertly navigating this complexity is mission critical. Still, legal only enables core activities. Given the natural preference to allocate finite resources to core activities, the gap grows, and will continue to widen, between business needs and the legal resources available to satisfy those needs.
The conventional mechanisms for addressing more business needs with relatively fewer legal resources involve reducing/controlling legal labor costs (e.g.,insourcing, discounts). Right sourcing is essential but fundamentally concerned with the unit economics of legal labor—i.e., how much the labor costs. Right sourcing is necessary but not sufficient to bend the cost curve long term because it does not address increasing demand.
6. Insourcing alone is not a viable, long-term approach.
Insourcing delivers immediate savings while enhancing proximity/accessibility. But insourcing has natural limits with headcount requests triggering objections that extend beyond the fiscal math of whether internal resources are less expensive than analogous external resources. Headcount is subject to soft and hard constraints, especially during periods of economic turmoil when savings pressure is most acute. Headcount growth also creates its own inertia and comes at the cost of agility.
7. Sustainable spend optimization is a more calibrated objective than immediate savings.
The path of least resistance has been to take advantage of simple labor arbitrage and capture associated savings. But the path of least resistance leads to path dependence. Short-term easy is long-term hard. While cost discipline is essential business hygiene, the only viable path forward is optimizing resource allocation over an extended time horizon. If the time horizon remains right now, there will never be adequate investment in sustainably driving business outcomes at scale and pace.
8. To meet business needs, the legal function must solve for scale, internally and externally.
The only way to do more with less is to get more from less. Resources must therefore be allocated to projects that progressively reduce the ratio of legal-resource inputs to business outputs—i.e., moving beyond the unit economics of legal labor to the unit economics of enterprise outcomes. This requirement extends to the selection and active management of external providers.
9. Traditional preferred-provider relationships are too ambiguous and too amorphous to drive adequate investments in innovation.
Voicing vague expectations that preferred providers innovate because they have the opportunity to serially compete for uncertain, heterogenous mandates does not result in the requisite focus and investment. The commercial context needs to change to drive service-model innovation. Clients, explicitly and implicitly, set the commercial context.
10. A matter is not always the appropriate unit, and law firms are not the only viable suppliers.
Matters can be packaged into portfolios. So, too, can their component parts (e.g., diligence, document review). Managed-service relationships with law firms are entirely feasible, as are relationships with law-firm alternatives (e.g., ASLPs).
Electronic discovery. Diligence. Mediations and arbitrations. Court reporting. Experts. There is all manner of direct and indirect costs that, in aggregate, present immediate savings opportunities. A holistic view of legal spend is a must. Otherwise, the design of the preferred-provider program will be compromised in an effort to meet immediate savings targets.
12. Economic uncertainty and unprecedented automation opportunities have only accelerated an inevitable reckoning.
The broader economic climate has subjected legal spend to heightened scrutiny. Meanwhile, the explosion of interest in Generative AI has recalibrated expectations of how knowledge work should be delivered while also introducing net new legal considerations in supporting the business’s own efforts to modernize operations—i.e., further widening gap between business needs and legal resources.
13. There is no change without change.
Your system is optimized to produce its current outputs. Dissatisfaction with those outputs is necessary but not sufficient to drive change. If you want different, you must accept different. Different decisions. Different decision makers. Different ways of working. Different definitions of success. This includes buying differently—different criteria driving different relationships with different suppliers and supplier types.
14. Meaningful change requires leadership, choice, work, attention, and patience.
If it were easy, it would already be done. The longer you play the short game, the harder the long game becomes. There are no viable shortcuts. Under-resourced, aspirational exercises on infeasible timelines consume scarce resources. Your objectives require sustained focus and true leadership buy-in. Leadership includes taking your people places they would never go on their own. Buy-in means there is a price to paid in political capital to ensure skeptics—of which there will be many—disagree & commit rather than acquiesce & undermine.
15. There are no risk-free, tradeoff-free alternatives, including the status quo.
You are placing bets on an uncertain future. Big bets should be interrogated thoroughly. Succumbing to inertia is betting big that the current trajectory is sustainable. It is not enough to surface the very real risks and tradeoffs of change without subjecting the choice not to change to the same scrutiny. A risk-free, tradeoff-free option will not present itself by process of elimination.
FLAWED PREMISES
The flawed premise general to knowledge work is it should be organized like physical work—with static roles repeatedly performing the same sets of activities. Under this premise, knowledge outputs are a product of labor inputs—more output requires more labor. Most knowledge work, however, should be organized around projects that produce knowledge and embed that knowledge upstream in business processes to improve outcomes, velocity, and leverage (i.e., compliance by design).[1] Alternatively, projects should produce scalable programs that optimize resources to sustainably enable the enterprise.
Critically, these are premises. These premises predate the formation of the legal function. Enterprises create law departments to serve as captive law firms—and then continue to characterize them as such. The enterprise sets the time horizon (i.e., right now) on which law departments operate. While leverage/technology/innovation receive regular lip service, projects to produce leverage are almost always subordinate to performing time-sensitive legal work, which is all consuming. In-house lawyers are doing precisely what they are trained, hired, and ordered to do. This is sufficient until it isn’t—when workload outstrips capacity and budget.
Ultimately, a legal function starved of the resources required to meet increasing business needs will fail to meet business needs. As long as the relationship between business needs and legal labor remains linear—i.e., an increase in business needs results in a proportionate increase in the demand for legal labor—the probability of not meeting business needs will be high because the probability of adequate resourcing will be low.
THE ENDLESS SAVINGS CYCLE
FRUSTRATIONS: EXTERNAL LEGAL RESOURCE MANAGEMENT
Enterprise demand for legal services is largely inelastic in the near term. If an enterprise decides to cut spend on marketing or R&D, those cuts hold until different decisions are made. But periods of economic turmoil often generate net new legal work—e.g., COVID-era policy paroxysms; navigating a RIF. Regulatory reporting requirements do not abate. Lawsuits and investigations are not put on hold because their target desires to control costs. Indeed, even if an enterprise experiences an extended period of fiscal stagnation, relative legal needs still increase due to net new regulations it did not ask for—i.e., many inescapable legal demand drivers are exogenous to the enterprise.
2. The lack of control is paired with a lack of predictability.
There are an estimated 5 million regulatory bodies worldwide. New regulatory requirements come from all directions. Same for lawsuits and investigations. Likewise, enterprise pivots responsive to a shifting economic landscape are business drivers of legal needs not within the law department’s ambit of control. Volume volatility is exacerbated by the often intractable nature of the work itself. Legal-laden business activities frequently entail interacting with independent third parties—regulators, counterparties to contracts, opposing parties in lawsuits—whose ungovernable decisions are cost drivers.
Information is data organized to be useful for decision making. While legal billing data is abundant, legal pricing information is scarce. Part of this is the semi-intractable nature of legal work involving independent parties, known unknowns, and unknown unknowns. Part of this is bad historical data habits, including the lack of industry-wide data standards (why everyone should support SALI). Part of this is intentional opacity. For example, the only semi-reliable source for law-firm rate benchmarking, Thomson Reuter’s Peer Monitor, is not available to law firms’ corporate clients. And it is not just pricing. Most settlements (i.e., outcomes that typically dwarf the direct expenditures on legal services) are private and therefore currently impervious to analytics outside the enterprise’s own limited data set.Fortunately, very few contracts, intellectual property protections, policy decisions, etc. are ever subject to legal action. Unfortunately, this means the quality thereof is rarely stress tested. Because we can’t benchmark outcomes, we possess poor proxies for lawyer quality—not an experiential good but, rather, a credence good often treated as a Veblen good. The result is overreliance on relationships and the proxies of brand/pedigree/price.
Despite the absence of solid empirical measures, lawyer quality often has material business impact. Thus, not only is enterprise demand for legal services near-term inelastic, so, too, is the supply of lawyers able to properly meet that demand. Before the modern era, essentially all lawyers were external. The dominant practice was to source all legal work to a single law firm. The rise of large law departments fundamentally changed not only the locus of legal service delivery (most of which now occurs internally at large enterprises) but the approach to legal buy.
5. Search costs and switching costs are high.
Finding a good, fit-to-purpose lawyer can be a challenge. Finding an equivalent lawyer at a materially lower price point is even more challenging because of the way market prices work. Moreover, even if an equivalent lawyer is identified at a lower price point than an incumbent, the new provider must be onboarded. Ramp-up is resource intensive. Reaching minimum fluency with organizational context commands scarce attention from both internal and external resources. Onboarding new external resources creates drag in areas that often demand speed and consumes bandwidth in a bandwidth-constrained environment.
6. Legal spend can be significant in raw dollars but is often a rounding error in relative dollars, especially in comparison to the priorities legal spend supports.
Among Global 200 companies, total legal spend averages ~0.10% of revenue. The internal/external split is roughly 50/50. External spend is therefore ~0.05% of revenue. Thus, a savings goal of 20% on external spend is ~0.001% of revenue (i.e., $10 for every $1,000,000 in revenue). No company is average. Many spend much more. Most have different splits. But the bottom line is that incremental savings on external legal spend has de minimis significance for the corporate bottom line even if the savings translate into rather large numbers in raw dollars (as everything does at large enterprises; this is known as denominator blindness). Meanwhile, the initiatives this spend is directed at supporting range from annoyingly necessary to strategically vital, with orders of magnitude more business impact than some small variance in total legal spend.
PREFERRED-PROVIDER PROGRAMS OFTEN FAIL TO DELIVER
Each new provider adds administrative effort in terms of onboarding and oversight—from paying invoices to ensuring compliance with data-security obligations. In theory, consolidating work with a subset of preferred providers alleviates administrative overload and enables the enterprise to concentrate its buying power to drive down costs—fewer negotiations, more negotiating leverage.
Countless awards have been won by law departments who have drastically reduced their provider count and secured fat discounts that translate into spectacular savings. There are, however, many reasons these achievements often fail to sustainably deliver the desired results in practice, including:-
The savings are fake.
Simplistic savings math introduces perverse incentives to choose the most expensive option and then spend as much as possible—every incremental discounted hour simultaneously contributes to total spend and total “savings.”
As soon as demanding discounts became a norm, law firms, as rational economic actors, raised their rates to create flexibility to offer differentiated pricing.
A buyer of consequence who has never exercised its negotiating leverage to maximize discounts can secure major concessions, especially since firms have raised rates to offer differential pricing to other clients already demanding discounts. But once you’ve negotiated suppliers down to their lowest rate, the only direction thereafter is up, unless you are willing to switch to a lower-cost provider—a more fraught endeavor than capturing discounts from incumbents.
The goals are in tension.
The fewer providers, the more practice-area and jurisdictional coverage each needs to cover—i.e., larger firms must be included for sufficient scope. Law-firm size is positively correlated with law-firm price tag. Larger firms are generally more expensive. Thus, in traditional programs, tradeoffs are unavoidable. An expansive network of preferred providers does little to reduce administrative burden. Yet a narrow network of preferred providers often skews toward larger, more expensive firms.
Administrative burden is more redistributed than reduced.
Selecting preferred providers is a project (work) that results in a program. For the program to function, it must be administered (more work). Administration includes ensuring the program actually awards preference—far from a natural occurrence.
Frequently, a small team is instructed to design a preferred-provider program in a vacuum, but they are not empowered to award mandates to the selected providers. Rather, other in-house personnel retain selection discretion, and exercise it as they always have. The outcome is that work is distributed as before. The project is pure waste excepting the discounts secured from providers the enterprise already engaged on a regular basis—i.e., a self-aware project charter would have limited the scope to negotiating discounts with repeat providers.
Alternatively, selection discretion is curtailed. But this increases the burden of handling novel work. A parade of unfamiliar issues is a by-product of the legal operating environment becoming more complex. Because prescience is in short supply, no providers are empaneled for the purpose of handling the unforeseeable. And search costs are higher within an artificially circumscribed talent pool.[2]
The main drivers remain unaddressed.
Billing rate is not price, but, rather, a multiplier of the primary variable: hours. Hours are a manifestation of demand. Most preferred-provider programs do nothing to control demand nor the relationship between demand and hours (i.e., ‘how’ work gets done). If demand continues to increase, so will outlays. A perfectly executed rate re-adjustment is, by definition, a one-time lift—driving providers down to market price. Market prices continue to increase. So, too, do hours. And, while there are lasting fiscal benefits to resetting the baseline, you will be on the same upward trajectory as before.
- Matter-level RFPs, including reverse auctions, to ensure providers compete on price
- Matter-level negotiations to further maximize price concessions
- Matter-level guardrails like budgets, caps, flat fees, or holdbacks to maintain price integrity
In sum, traditional preferred-provider programs can accomplish a fair amount in controlling relative costs, though are not automatically effective because of a natural skew towards larger, more expensive firms. Preferred providers programs that are effective in controlling costs tend to be far less effective at reducing administrative burden, and often increase it. And even successful cost control results in mostly one-time lifts that do not address demand drivers nor solve for scale—rather, the preoccupation with maximizing immediate savings crowds out efforts to drive systemic improvements with sustainable ROI.
WORK PACKAGING EXAMPLE
Work Packaging Example
In tandem with this programmatic approach, the in-house department undertook a project to automatically assemble and synthesize reports they’d previously manually collected and sent to outside counsel. Before the project, outside counsel expended an average of 8 hours per matter compiling the relevant, matter-specific information from disparate reports. After the project, outside counsel only require an average of 1 hour to review the automatically generated synthesis (the source materials are still provided in the delivery packet).
The in-house department also consolidated all attendant ediscovery with a single provider, establishing a specialized review team and iterating on technology-assisted review models that could be applied across matters in the portfolio.
Freed from the administrative burden of matter-by-matter firm selection and matter-level invoice reviews, as well as the communications overhead of dealing with so many firms, the in-house lawyers redirected their efforts to their own KPIs. Their objectives were to drive down(i) total volume on a relative basis (through root-cause analysis/prevention)and (ii) total cost of ownership (settlement values, internal resource load, business disruption). This entailed not only portfolio-level projects (e.g.,the automated assembly of the reports) with an emphasis on moving upstream into the business but also propagating firm-level best practices and innovations across their consolidated provider network.
The program will be re-assessed near the conclusion of the three-year term. The data strategy, knowledge assets, and tactical use of fallback firms should make the work more portable than it ever has been. But sustained investments in service delivery should rightfully earn incumbent firms a cumulative advantage on cost effectiveness when seeking renewal.
But not only matters. In the example, work was decomposed to permit the complementary packaging of tasks. Report assembly was automating a specific task. Unbundling and re-packaging ediscovery was bringing economies of scale to a discrete set of tasks—and, in fact, the ediscovery carve out was applied to other litigation profiles—indicative of the opportunity to blend diverse supplier types (i.e., not only law firms) even within a single matter.
The direct cost savings were eventually significant but deliberately delayed. The program was cost neutral in year one. That decision, combined with the volume and multi-year term (i.e., revenue certainty), afforded the law firms the opportunity to make the investments necessary to ensure the work would remain profitable even after payments declined in years two and three. The guardrails protected the firms from the downside risk of too much volume, and the client from the risk of too little. Volume also insulated the firms from pervasive matter-to-matter variances (the law of large numbers) while the flat fee provided the client with predictability.
The savings were also delayed because the law department funded the automated report assembly project instead of capturing the more immediate savings available from hiring internal resources to manually synthesize the reports.
Humans are exceptionally plug-and-play. Labor arbitrage offers the quickest route to cost reduction. Replacing eight hours of billable time per matter, the savings math supporting new hires was strong. The savings from labor-centric insourcing also would have been guaranteed. The cost of the automation project was more than monetary expense, it introduced delay and the real risk of failure. The bet, however, was worth it because while insourcing would have produced guaranteed savings, it was also guaranteed to never scale (more volume would have demanded proportionately more human hours).
Moreover, the law department did not maximize cost control. They expressly eschewed ‘shadow bills’ for the purpose of calculating savings—a common practice that disincentivizes innovation.[3] Thus, they sacrificed the putative savings of capturing the manufactured delta from pairing aggressive rate increases with aggressive rate discounting. Under this alternative math, it is conceivable the law department could have shown even better by negotiating on a matter-by-matter basis.
[3] Many law departments are obsessed with “winning” and “losing” flat-fee arrangements. They use shadow bills to baseline. How much would it have cost under a traditional billable hour approach? If the shadow bills indicate a matter would have been less expensive under hourly fees, that is a loss. Some law departments have even asked their firms to write them a check to make up the difference, and are perversely proud of this fact. Such zero-sum thinking disincentivizes any effort by law firms to reduce hours or enable the use of lower cost resources.
Even more explicitly, the law department did not select the lowest bids. They selected competitive bids from firms best suited to the new approach (service-model innovation, collaboration, accountability for continuous improvement) and whose genuine expertise made them most likely to secure superior net outcomes for the enterprise (because the monetary stakes far exceed the legal fees).
Further, they did not take full advantage of the portfolio arrangements, which were only “near exclusive.” Much as manufacturers will send 5-10% of orders to a secondary supplier so they are not beholden to a single source of failure, the law department siphoned off a pre-determined percentage of portfolio matters to experiment and maintain relationships with fallback firms.
The narrow use of fallback firms was one of many ways the law department chose not to maximize administrative ease. While they eliminated much of the matter-level administrative load (from RFPs to invoices), they added new administrative requirements with the KPIs, data strategy, knowledge assets, and continuous-improvement initiatives. And that was once the program was launched. The administrative investment in designing and implementing the program was far greater than constructing a panel.
The biggest lift, however, was changing internal behavior—alignment is bidirectional, not unilateral; improvement is about much more than pressuring law firms to bend. There were many tradeoffs and hiccups. Optimizing the aggregate performance of the portfolio in the service of sustainably improving business outcomes was an alien concept that took time to be internalized. Many tenured lawyers would still readily revert to the status quo ante because task-oriented oversite remains more in line with their professional skillset. They were also not fond of losing dominion over law firm selection. These autonomy-inclined professionals subsequently made a sport of identifying where the lawyer they would have chosen would have hypothetically outperformed the lawyer assigned by the portfolio firm. Hyperfocus on individual lawyer execution of isolated tasks was symptomatic of what proved to be a generally challenging transition from micro-management to macro-management. Did this one lawyer do this one thing exactly as I would have liked? is a more comfortable question than What directions are the KPIs moving in, and why?
The internal and external change management required was considerable. The system remains imperfect. But it is better. This tranche of work is now on a more sustainable trajectory, oriented towards continuous improvement over a reasonable time horizon, and well calibrated to long-term enterprise enablement.
WORK PACKAGING 101
To be properly packaged, work must be sorted. Work sorting extends across the entire value chain (i.e., in-house, too) and includes:
01 Identification
02 Segmentation
03 Decomposition
Moreover, portfolio design decisions must be tuned towards the appropriate objectives. Portfolios, like panels, are not ends in themselves. As with panels, maximizing near-term savings and administrative ease are just as likely to prove long-term suboptimal. The objective remains sustainable spend optimization over a reasonable time horizon in the service of enterprise enablement at scale and pace. In applicable circumstances, the portfolio is merely a more functional organizational approach than the matter-by-matter friction attendant to traditional provider relationships.
TOWARDS INTEGRATED LAW
Factor introduced the category of “Integrated Law” because labels like New Law, law company, alternative legal service provider, and managed-service provider proved inadequate.[4] Integrated Law aims to combine the expertise of traditional law firms, the cost efficiency of managed services, and the close business alignment of in-house. Integrated Law teams aren’t outsourced, they’re embedded.
- Scale Complexity: work that is complex due to its volume.
- Legal Complexity: work that is complex because it requires specialized expertise.
- Systemic Complexity: work that is complex because it requires an understanding of, and alignment with, the organization’s culture, strategies, systems, and processes.
- in-house departments address systemic complexity because of proximity to the business;
- law firms address legal complexity because of specialized expertise;
- managed-service providers address scale complexity because they are purpose built to handle high-volume, repetitive work.
“make everything as simple as possible but no simpler”
Our world is not so simple. Oversimplification has resulted in misconceptions like the pervasive belief that law departments are being buried by an avalanche of routine tasks. Law departments are being buried. There is an avalanche of tasks (scale complexity). But many tasks are not routine—i.e., many tasks demand specialized domain expertise (legal complexity) and/or organizational context (systemic complexity). Indivisible and multi-dimensional, these tasks reflect the tangled reality that complexities frequently overlap and intersect in ways that confound simple solutions. Many managed-service outsourcing efforts have underdelivered because a simplicity assumption drove the selection and subsequent hands-off management of the least expensive option rather than the selection of—and subsequent integration push with—the provider most capable of cost-effectively producing complex legal work at scale.
“make everything as simple as possible but no simpler”
“complex ≠ impossible”
“complex ≠ impossible”
Recurring transactional work is usually too high volume for the expense of traditional law-firm arrangements. Much high-volume contracting is also often too complex, too high touch, and too organizationally specific for traditional low-cost managed-service providers. Contracting has therefore largely fallen to internal resources and, by far, consumes the largest percentage of personnel time in most law departments. But, as we explored at the outset, internal resources end up subject to headcount restraints, even beyond their budgetary constraints—as business needs perennially outpace legal resources.
Integrated Law combines the logic of external relationships (volume and costs remain linked), the focus/accountability of a purpose-built enterprise (complex legal work at scale is, literally, their business), and the advantages of proximity—delivering work inside the client ecosystem, aligned to enterprise needs, goals and operating models. Integrated Law teams embed within client systems and function, for all practical purposes, as a part of the in-house legal team, except with easier access to incremental resources—flexing up during high-volume periods and down during lulls to ameliorate the peak-load problem.
Yet, as embedded as they are, Integrated Law providers remain third parties. If they are not performant… if they are not investing in innovation to improve unit economics over time…if they cease being the best available option…if…, you can switch. Not painlessly. But far less painfully than trying to transform or move on from internal teams who are not executing or whose labor-intensive current state is outmoded. Integrated Law delivers the benefits of embeddedness without the encumbrances of permanent hires.
INDISPENSABLE IN-HOUSE LAWYWERS
Embedded advisory is about being in the room where it happens—i.e., influencing the most significant business decisions. Embedded advisory exists at the point of greatest overlap between legal complexity, systemic complexity, and material business impact. In-house lawyers are ideally positioned to pair subject matter expertise with a deep understanding of organizational context to support the business in strategically placing its biggest bets.
Bets, by definition, entail risk. Declaring to a business decisionmaker “well, there’s a risk” is essentially a content-free statement. Every business decision balances a variety of enterprise risks, only some of which are legal in nature. Attempting to eliminate risk, or minimize risk in ways that ignore net business impact, is how legal can be sidelined as the Department of No or the Department of Slow.
Given headcount constraints, we need to purposefully create space for embedded advisory. That begins with self-awareness as to what is and is not advisory work. Many in-house lawyers are inclined to label whatever they do as “advice” and therefore not amenable to any form of systemization that would change their work mix. Many in-house lawyers, for example, would describe their involvement in repeat transactional matters as “advising on contracts.” This frames each contract as a matter of first impression demanding the formulation of one-off advice. That is, they correctly recognize the work is legally complex but incorrectly conclude it is therefore immune to being delivered at scale.
From a resource allocation perspective, the consequence of this conclusion is reduced capacity for true enterprise enablement in the form of embedded advisory. From a sustainability perspective, this category error perpetuates the presumption that once workload exceeds labor capacity the only option becomes purchasing proportionately more labor—i.e., leaning harder into the untenable, linear relationship between business needs and lawyer hours.
PREFERRED-PROVIDER PANELS PERSIST
Not all work packaged as portfolios will have the business proximity necessary for true integration. Not all work is amenable to packaging due to volume, size, scope, frequency, and variability. Not all work amenable to packaging will be packaged immediately—these are labor-intensive projects that should be sequenced. Not all providers who handle substantial volumes of the enterprise’s legal work will be awarded portfolios. Many providers awarded portfolios will also handle non-portfolio work. Any provider entrusted with highly sensitive work is subject to enhanced data-security scrutiny. Any provider relied on to deliver broad and diverse swathes of the enterprise’s legal work should have a global rate card and be aligned with the enterprise’s ways of working.
In short, preferred providers should not be limited to portfolio relationships. Portfolios are merely a key subset of preferred-provider relationships.
As with packaging, form should follow function. Work sorting should precede supplier sorting. Rather than starting with an arbitrary target number of providers, the work to be allocated should inform the rationalization of the supplier base.
Invariably, even with the best efforts at rationalization, a large organization with myriad, disparate legal needs will end up with an extensive provider network. Within the confines of a panel, reducing the provider count only means partnering with bigger providers offering broader coverage—i.e., fewer providers does not necessarily shrink the size of the provider base. Reducing the provider count also does not reduce search costs, it increases them—because, traditionally, a global search is more apt to quickly surface fit-to-purpose options than a local search within a circumscribed talent pool that may not include an ideal fit (hence the necessity of step outs).
MARKETPLACES
When confronted with novelty, the default within law departments is for the responsible in-house lawyer to email their primary contacts at their primary law firms asking, “Can you handle this?” Generally, the law-firm contact responds promptly with an emphatic “Yes!” before forwarding the email to their entire firm inquiring, “Who can handle this?”
At present, the choice is between high manual search costs (finding the right fit) or suboptimal resource decisions (finding the best fit within a subset of options). Thus, following the standard path of information accessibility, expert curation must eventually be paired with tech-enabled search.
Step outs will be reduced. Step outs will not be eliminated.
No panel, no matter how robust, well-constructed, or easy to search will ever provide complete coverage for every legal issue that may arise. But an open-world approach to filling gaps in the panel introduces the same challenges—lack of vetting, lack of cost control—that motivated the creation of the panel in the first instance.
Even with a rigorous, multi-stage vetting process that has a ~10% acceptance rate, Marketplace has onboarded thousands of lawyers onto the platform. This rigorous vetting supersedes the reliance on brand/price as proxies for quality. Searchability enhances discoverability. Marketplace is an enabler for, and therefore home to, BigLaw refugees who have formed boutiques or struck out as solos—same lawyers, lower price point. Marketplace provides large clients access to small, cost-effective firms sans the attendant burden of managing a massive, fluid supplier base.
Like Scout, Marketplace substantially reduces search costs. For large law departments, Marketplace functions as an extension of Scout. To the extent a Scout search turns up wanting (no fit-to-purpose resources within the preferred-provider network), the search can be continued on Marketplace.
To maintain fiscal rigor, Marketplace offers tools for running RFPs among top candidates and setting budgets with selected providers. To eliminate administrative burden, Marketplace centralizes billing so lawyers from the platform do not need to be onboarded for invoicing purposes.
MARKETPLACE AS A SPEND CATEGORY
Calling back to the origin story of preferred-provider programs, the in-house counsel predisposition to hire lawyers, not law firms has merit. Lawyer quality matters. Quality includes fit. But the aggregate impact of hiring lawyers, not law firms, is the absence of cost discipline aggravated by the considerable administrative burden of managing a massive, fluid supplier network.
Introducing a preferred-provider program has its own drawbacks. The logic of limiting provider count militates toward empaneling the biggest firms with the broadest coverage. But brand is only a marginally useful proxy for quality, which is often uneven within large firms. And while these firms are big, they tend to offer economies of scope without corresponding economies of scale. Size therefore tends to correlate with expense.
Moreover, in a pre-Scout world, artificially limiting the talent pool dramatically increases search costs. Even in a post-Scout world, step outs remain necessary because no panel can cover every contingency. Indeed, efforts to enlarge the panel only re-introduce the administrative burden the panel was intended to alleviate while also forcing many providers to jump through onboarding hoops only to never be engaged—wasting everyone’s (legitimately) precious time.
A well-crafted marketplace obviates much of this. In-house counsel can hire lawyers (not just law firms) from a pre-vetted network (quality control) with a broad mix of practice areas and jurisdictions. The law department can implement price thresholds (cost control) and take advantage of centralized billing (administrative ease) without the added effort and friction associated with vetting and onboarding.
In fact, if in-house counsel identify a non-panel lawyer they would like to consider for an opportunity, it should be easier for everyone involved to send that lawyer to the marketplace than have them directly onboarded to the enterprise system. This approach is also superior for external lawyers because participation in the marketplace makes them accessible to other enterprise clients—i.e., they can benefit even if the organization that recommended the marketplace never ends up using them, as is so often the case with preferred-provider programs that award no preference.
Where a single enterprise has reasons to limit the number of panel firms due to administrative load, a marketplace thrives on network effects. Every additional lawyer and every additional client amplify the benefits of the network for all its participants. As long as vetting discipline and solid data practices are maintained, a marketplace should be the preferred method for sourcing novel, intermittent, and irregular needs.
On repeat and/or larger matters, the need remains to hire law firms, not only individual lawyers. Just as portfolios do not replace preferred-provider relationships, a marketplace does not supplant a panel. A marketplace is a complement configured for certain matter profiles. A marketplace therefore enables a more targeted preferred-provider program because the marketplace absorbs much of the flotsam and jetsam that frustrate program design. And, of course, repeat providers can graduate from a marketplace to preferred provider or portfolio arrangements when and where their work profile merits mutual investment in such a relationship.
This all requires investment, in one form or another. A marketplace is not free. Priori’s charges are transparent and substantially less than the hidden markups for traditional legal staffing—a sub-genre of external hire Marketplace also addresses. These fees are offset by the enhanced access to more price-competitive resources and cover the costs of vetting, administration, and tech—costs that would have been incurred anyway but not so clearly accounted for.
There are no cost-free alternatives. There are more cost-effective and less cost-effective uses of finite resources. Effectiveness is, in part, defined by perspectives and priorities, which not only govern how you hire but whom.
DIVERSITY
At core, DEI initiatives are about meritocracy, not charity. DEI efforts require effort to overcome arbitrary impediments to meritocracy resulting from systemic biases that distribute advantages and disadvantages with no basis in merit. Any notion that achieving diversity requires sacrificing quality is confused. Explicably, much of that confusion stems from the reality that systemic distortions mean more effort is required to identify diverse talent—i.e., search costs are higher. There are no competent, diverse lawyers is almost certainly false in any given instance.[5] I, personally, don’t know competent, diverse lawyers is often true, and a problem well worth solving.
It is not enough, however, to have the means to identify diverse talent. To honor your DEI commitments, you must be purposeful in hiring diverse talent. This responsibility cannot be outsourced. You must hold yourselves accountable. Do your own internal hiring patterns reflect your DEI commitments? Are your DEI commitments manifest in your direct hiring of external lawyers? As you refresh your preferred-provider program, the latter question is of particular moment.
Unfortunately, the primary point of emphasis in many law department DEI initiatives has been indirect hiring of diverse professionals. There is absolutely a place for not only understanding but impacting how work is allocated to ensure that diverse professionals are staffed on your matters and entrusted with tasks that further their career development. But it is a supplement to, not a substitute for, directing walletshare to diverse talent in the first instance. Who you hire directly is also easier to track than ‘who you hire assigns work to’ because of the common challenge of self-identification mucking up what is already a data-rich but information-poor environment.
Moreover, while there is much to recommend not just reporting requirements but actual requirements to staff matters with diverse professionals, there is an often unappreciated tension with the parallel pursuit of maximal price concessions. Clients with the buying power to demand diverse professionals be staffed on their matters are also the clients with the buying power to secure the deepest discounts and impose the most rigid commercial constraints. This results in the staffing of diverse professionals on the least profitable matters with the lowest revenue per hour and the worst realizations. Diverse professionals’ financial performance and their attendant case for career advancement suffer when well-intentioned DEI initiatives are paired with aggressive cost control.
I did, in fact, just suggest you spend more money to promote diversity. I stand by it. But if that is a bridge too far, then invest even more effort in utilizing minority- and women-owned firms or, at least, diverse partners from non-mega firms, to make good on your DEI commitments while simultaneously lowering the average price point of external expertise.
Valuing diversity means paying for diversity, from incurring search costs to directing walletshare. “Value” is not defined as what customers say they want but, rather, what customers are willing to pay for. If it is a priority, it is worth paying for. Otherwise, it is merely a nice-to-have.
Priorities function as the organizing principles of resource allocation. Money>Words.
EXTRAORDINARY SPEND
In certain respects, accountability without authority is intrinsic to the legal function. Much is beyond the law department’s ambit of control but within its sphere of responsibility. Still, it is best practice to properly account for extraordinary spend—singular exigencies with material business impact and substantial budgetary implications that often warrant bypassing programmatic sourcing controls.
Which is fine, in theory. It is the enterprise’s money. But, in practice, even when procedural discipline is maintained, big surprises can blow up the law department’s budget and make genuine fiscal diligence appear to be profligacy. Extraordinary spend is important to track for future discussions around proper stewardship of corporate resources—accounting records tend to outlast both human and institutional memories.
For our present purposes, however, extraordinary spend should be segregated for internal accounting simply because it is not helpful for planning and tracking. To the extent future KPIs will be assessed with respect to percentage spend on portfolio partnerships, marketplace resources, different supplier types, etc., extraordinary spend is noise that will obscure our signals of progress, or lack thereof, as the program matures.
SOLVING FOR NOW
Unless handled deftly, now is not an ideal time to be re-imagining a multi-year revamp of the preferred-provider program. The understandable temptation will be to configure the program to satisfy urgent expectations. It would be nonsensical to pretend these expectations can be ignored. But it would be unfortunate if short-term easy resulted in even more long-term hard.
Ironically, indiscriminate cost cutting is cruelest to the most discriminating departments. Lean legal teams that have spent years effectively negotiating external providers down to market prices seemingly have little room to maneuver without reducing service levels. Moreover, the enduring rate obsession means the most common lever pressed in these scenarios—demanding deeper discounts from incumbent law firms—tends to have minimal impact. To the extent cost-cutting mandates are merely performative, some superficial rate concessions may be sufficient. If there are hard fiscal targets, however, discounts will prove insufficient.
To not sacrifice program objectives on the altar of short termism, a more holistic and sustainable approach to immediate cost takeout is required.
Labor arbitrage still works. Building on the previous sections, an expedient path to utilizing both Integrated Law and Marketplace is to lift and shift work from expensive external resources to less expensive external resources. This is classic labor arbitrage, which, again, is effective in the near term (the focus of this section) even if it is necessary but not sufficient over the long term.
Again, tasks are frequently the most useful level of resolution. Many right-sourcing opportunities materialize once an unbundling frame broadens our possibilities. For example, a matter type that is considered 95% routine labor and 5% high-end expertise might currently be sourced to a Tier 2 firm because their labor costs are materially lower than a Tier 1 firm. In a re-configured delivery dynamic, a Tier 1 expert (higher end expertise) can be paired with Integrated Law or Marketplace resources (even more economical labor costs) to improve quality while still reducing total external expenditures.
Efficiency gains can be impactful. Another route to reducing external expenditures is to keep more work in-house. Handling more work internally may seem unpromising in an environment where hiring is frozen (can’t add headcount to substitute for external hours) and in-house resources are already stretched. Moreover, the suggestion to handle more work in-house may also seem incongruent with all the preceding warnings about the limits of insourcing (still accurate). There are, however, material differences between adding headcount and making existing headcount more efficient (remember this word).
Assuming internal resources have an average of 1600 eligible hours for producing outputs that would otherwise flow to external resource and an average external resource cost of $300/hr, below is a chart of the cost-takeout impact of efficiency gains.
Cost takeout, however, will not necessarily manifest as spend reduction because the volume of work is not static. In one world, spend could fall simply because volume does. In another world, spend could increase even with substantial cost takeout because volume increases at an even greater rate (i.e., demand drivers can never be ignored).
Moreover, these are average improvements across individuals, teams, and workstreams. One role within a team could be transformed while another does not change. One team might translate every hour gained into multiple hours that no longer flow through to external resources while a different team’s workload has no impact on external resource utilization. An hour retained by one workstream may translate into $800/hr in external cost takeout while another may translate into only $150/hr.
You are encouraged to do more granular calculations tailored to your context. A compelling benefit of comprehensive work sorting is understanding the various strands of your value chain: how business activity drives legal demand and then how demand flows through, or not, to external resources at various price points.
Resource preservation math is counterintuitive because efficiency ≠ productivity.
The foregoing highlights that the local resource interests of the department are not perfectly aligned with the global productivity needs of the business. This is unavoidable. Yet to the extent freeing up departmental resources is the only presently available path to meeting evolving business needs, the math also surfaces the potential impact of tackling low-end friction even if the apparent productivity gains present as paltry. The math informs decisions about which improvement initiatives to prioritize, and how to appropriately characterize ROI.
Long-term, productivity matters most for meeting business needs. Near-term, efficiency is what frees up finite resources. In normal times, we pursue efficiency plays to unlock resources to direct towards projects that drive productivity. In not normal times, we identify efficiency opportunities to tread water while achieving cost takeout.
From a cost-takeout perspective, the math also informs how to characterize and prioritize improvement initiatives among your external providers.
There are many different external spend optimization opportunities that can deliver near-term savings. Law firms consume the largest chunk of external legal spend. But there are many other direct costs and passthroughs that, in aggregate, represent significant sums (again, a matter is not always the proper level of resolution). Electronic discovery. Due diligence. Mediations & arbitrations. Experts. Court reporting. Subpoena responses. Corporate governance. Routine IP management. These are the low-hanging fruit in an environment where we have already been applying maximum downward pressure on law firm pricing for years and are unlikely to squeeze out much more near-term cost savings from longtime incumbents.
There are many levers to be pressed. Avoid Maslow’s Hammer, which makes everything look like a nail. Doubling down on extracting price concessions from incumbent law firms will not double the results. Spend optimization across the entire value chain can contribute immediate savings that do not sacrifice the long term for the near term.
Though the near term certainly projects to be nothing if not interesting.
ACCELERANTS: GEN AI AND ECONOMIC TURBULENCE
The revamp of the preferred-provider program comes at pivot point in the evolution of legal services. According to SixParsecs and Factor, GenAI is posed to reshape 80% of the corporate legal wallet:
There is little time to waste. The world is only speeding up.
PARTING THOUGHTS
With respect to sustainability, every law department should be able to calculate the percentage of their total spend currently dedicated to projects that once complete will progress their ability to meet business needs at scale and pace.[8] As part of that calculation, every law department should know what percentage of their external spend is flowing to relationships that are designed to scale (e.g., portfolios, Integrated Law).
Progress starts with creativity, graduates to heuristic, matures to system, and, ideally, is ultimately reduced to code. Creativity is about invention. Heuristic is about judgment. System is about repetition. Code is about automation. Law departments traditionally get stuck in the middle, somewhere between heuristic and system, where judgment borne from training + experience remains imperative for competent decision making.
To get unstuck, law departments need to foster greater creativity in building scalable systems. Being creative will include accepting that, by definition, no truly new idea can be proven in advance analytically and that punctuational change is not possible without experiments bold enough to fail. Which is all far easier said than done. It is certainly not easy to re-tool the machine without ever being permitted to take it offline. We, however, are supposed to be expert at doing the hard things well.
LexFusion is here to help, not to judge. Perfection serves as a useful target but an impossible standard. We’re all in this together. And we can assure you no one else has it all figured out either. We wish you the very best.
Fortis Fortuna Aduivat